An autonomous research institute under the Ministry of Finance

 

National Institute of Public Finance and Policy NIPFP One pager
No. 8

May, 2014

Reforming Fossil Fuel Prices in India: Dilemma of a Developing Economy

MUKESH ANAND, Associate Professor, National Institute of Public Finance and Policy, New Delhi, India. email:mukesh.anand@nipfp.org.in

The Reserve Bank of India (RBI) has expressed concern that elimination of fuel subsidy could cause a spike in inflation.1 Elsewhere, it is estimated that a 10 per cent increase in price of crude petroleum could raise the wholesale price index (WPI) based inflation by 2 percentage points. 2 Price reform propositions for the fossil fuel sector often evoke sharp reaction.

 

Anand (2014) presents estimates for increase in total cost of farming resulting from a proposed change in fossil fuel prices. Use of fossil fuels in farming has direct and indirect components and increase in total costs is presented as a multiple of direct input costs of fossil fuels in farming. Direct input of fossil fuel constitutes purchase of diesel by farmers to run farm machinery and equipment. But, two important indirect linkages are through use of (a) fertilisers and (b) power or electricity.

 

Over time, direct use of fossil fuels on farms has risen and indirect use particularly for non-energy purposes is also growing. Column 6 in table 1 shows that despite significant decline over years, the magnitude of the multiple for total to direct use of fossil fuel in farming is quite large. But, fossil fuel and energy intensities are declining for the aggregate Indian economy (columns 3 and 4, table 2). However, these are rising for Indian agriculture (column 5, table 2). Thus, revision of fossil fuel prices acquires greater significance for Indian agriculture than for rest of the economy.

 

Expenditure incurred on purchase of fuel is a product of (a) number of units purchased and (b) price per unit. The economic impact of price increase of fossil fuels would also depend on the relative price structure for all inputs to produce a good or service. If all prices increase at the same rate, then relative prices are unchanged, and the proportion of fuel cost in total cost of product also remains unchanged. But, if price of fossil-fuels rises steeper than the average price of farm produce, then the proportion of fuel cost in total cost also rises. Conversely, if input price increases at a lower rate than output price, then input cost proportion in total cost is lowered.

 

Table 1: Direct and Indirect Use of Fossil-fuel on Farms (in ktoe)
Year Direct Use Indirect use in
(one stage removed only)
Total to Direct
Multiple
(2+3+4+5)/2
Proportion of Fin.
Cons. of Oil Pr. and
Nat. Gas in Agri. (%)
Power Fertilisers
Domestic Imported
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)
1990 1244 3852 9239 2813 13.8 2.1
1998 3719 7690 14713 3441 7.9 4.1
2007 6747 8064 12273 6521 5.0 5.0
2011 8022 10001 12952 9644 5.1 4.8


2 RBI (2011), Price Situation, Reserve Bank of India Monthly Bulletin, May 2011, pp 636-45. In partial setting, analogous outcome could derive from a 10 per cent depreciation in currency, leaving the international USD denominated price unchanged.

 

Download PDF

 

Table 2: Energy consumption and GDP in India
Year Primary Energy Supply in kgoOE per 1000 INR of GDP Final Consumption of Energy in kgoOE per 1000 INR of GDP of GDP at Constant 2004-5 Prices at Factor Cost
(crore INR)
Share of Agriculture in GDP at 2004-5 Prices, (%)
Total Fossil Fuels Economy Agriculture
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)
1990-1 23.50 13.01 18.67 1.40 1347889 29.5
1998-9 20.22 12.81 14.49 2.37 2087828 24.4
2007-8

15.52

10.75

10.29

2.40 3896636 16.8
2011-2 14.29 10.33 9.39 2.64 5243582 14.1

Source: GDP data from http://mospi.nic.in/Mospi_New/upload/NAS13.htm;

http://www.iea.org/statistics/statisticssearch/report/?country=INDIA&product=balances&year=2011

Notes: kgoOE: kilogram of oil equivalent; INR: Indian rupee; One crore equals 10 million or 100 lakhs. Column 5 does not include non-energy use of fossil fuels.

 

Data on price indices,3 to supplement quantity (or technical) use depicted in tables 1 and 2, reveals that with 1993-4 as base year (index = 100), in 1998-9 the index for fuel and power (148.5) grew slower than the index for food articles (159.4). But, in 2007-8, the index for fuel and power (338.9) grew significantly faster than the index for food articles (230.2). Thus, relative change in fossil fuel prices may have subdued the quantity multiple in 1998-9 but aggravated it in 2007-8.

 

These findings are validated by an alternative approach that utilises a three-sector input-output (I-O) model for the Indian economy representing farming, fossil fuels, and rest of economy in 1998-9 and 2007-8. Note that Indian I-O tables are value transactions and obviate the need to combine disparate assessment on quantity and price impacts.

 

The analysis reveals that in 2007-8, the direct input of fossil fuels in farming had grown 1.9 times its level in 1998-9. Further, fossil fuels sector is assessed to portray strong forward linkages. Thus, total effect of a given change in fossil fuel prices was (3.99) 6.7 times its direct impact in (1998-9) 2007-8.

 

Data collated from reports of Commission for Agricultural Costs and Prices (CACP) revealed that a 10 per cent increase in fossil fuel price could cause a 0.56 per cent average increase in direct input cost of farming. Total cost of farming then, could increase by (0.56*6.7=) 3.75 percentage points. Given the extant weight of commodities, the WPI could rise by about 4.3 percentage points with 0.7 percentage points contributed by farm sector.

 

Disaggregated analysis for the farming sector reveals significant differences across crops. But, even at the aggregate level, Anand (2014) has implications for monetary policy when one finds that second round effects (following from indirect use of fossil fuel in farming) on food inflation are significantly large. Further, there are profound implications for fiscal policy and administration, when reduction in fuel subsidy (or upward revision in fuel price) may have far-reaching implications for (a) setting support prices in agriculture, (b) circumscribing expenditure on food subsidy, and (c) administering the law on food security.

 

Reference

Anand, Mukesh 2014. Direct and Indirect Use of Fossil Fuels in Farming: Cost of Fuel-price Rise for Indian Agriculture, Working Paper No.132, NIPFP, New Delhi (February).

blog comments powered by Disqus